Why Populism? Globalism Isn’t Worth It

The Bank for International Settlements (BIS), the international body based in Basel, Switzerland that represents the world’s central banks, claims in its latest annual report that globalization is a “scapegoat” for rising inequality, as it launches a defense of closer cross-border ties and integration.

You didn’t get a copy and read every word of it? Well, the news might have been tucked away on the back pages of your local newspaper. It certainly didn’t make it to the big screen in your living room.

Here’s the gist: the bankers are worried. Very worried.

Truth is, globalization is ebbing while economic and political populism is surging. Globalists no longer provide the accepted set of rules for the political and economic order. Transnational, multilateral, and supranational organizations and their networks, experts, and regulators are everywhere on the defense. Cosmopolitan and globalist values are not ascendant.

As a matter of fact, national sovereignty is back and growing stronger, week by week, month by month. We see it most clearly in President Trump’s principled realism, called “America First.”

Like the 19th century version of populism that rallied against the gold standard, today’s economic populism is similarly anti-establishment, anti-elitist, and opposed to all forms of globalization and globalist governance.

Economic history and economic theory both provide strong reasons to suggest that the advanced stages of globalization are proof statements for the populist backlash, in both its right- and left-wing variants, and everywhere from Brexit and the Trump election to current European politics and unrest throughout Latin America.

Whether along ethnocultural cleavages or along income-class lines, these forms of populism are a predictable and logical result. It should surprise no one, including globalists, that the pendulum has swung so far in this direction.

In fact, analytically there are two sides to populism: demand and supply. Economic anxiety generates a base for populism but does not determine its particular political narrative—that storyline is left to various populist politicians and movements, which are on the rise today, worldwide. National greatness in one place does not diminish it in another place. There is no reason why all nations cannot articulate their individual greatness and in their self (national) interest interact in the world in a more peaceful and benign fashion.

Actually, it is the economics of trade and financial integration that provide the politically contentious backdrop to all globalization. Trade theory, such as the well-known Stolper-Samuelson theorem, shows that there are sharp distributional implications for open trade—in other words, free trade is not a “win-win.” Losers are inevitable.

And those who lose are generally low-skilled and unskilled workers. Trade liberalization raises the domestic price of exportables relative to importables. Go to any Walmart, if you want to check out this phenomenon first hand. Where is everything made?

There is an inherent form of redistribution at work here—the flip side of the benefits of trade. Overall as globalization advances, trade agreements themselves become more about redistributing and less about expanding the economic pie. The political fallout is clear: globalization, the opposite of national interest, has become more and more contentious, if not unsustainable.

The empirical evidence bears this out. From NAFTA, which has cost the United States some $3.5 trillion over the last decade, to the widening U.S.-China trade deficit, the American economy has enjoyed few overriding efficiency gains from globalization. What we have, instead, are large trade imbalances, income stagnation among middle earners, and other nasty social side-effects. Talk to any middle-class family or visit any town or factory in the affected dire areas and you can gain first-hand knowledge, up close and personal.

The overall benefits of globalization are zero to negative. Trade was supposed to be based on reciprocity and growth, but it turned out to be a sham.

Have those “left behind”—the “forgotten silent majority,” in Trumpian terms—been compensated from the clear effects of globalization? No, not really.

The benefits of international trade as originally argued by Adam Smith and its subsequent canonization ignores important historical differences. A displaced worker in our modern technological age (unlike a day-laborer or farmer in the 18th century) already has a home mortgage, car payments, tuition for his children, and lots of other overhead. Merely switching careers or retraining is not so simple for many people. Truthfully, it is more than difficult, especially for middle-aged workers who have generally worked one job and in one place.

The share of U.S. imports in GDP went from less than 7 percent in 1975 to more than 18 percent in recent years, but the imbalance has provided little of what’s called trade adjustment assistance.

Why? Because it is very costly—and politicians on all sides of the spectrum make a lot of promises they simply do not keep.

All economists know that trade causes job and income losses for some groups. Those same economists deride the notion of “fair trade” as a kind of fiction, but that’s clearly not the case as we see with anti-dumping rules and countervailing duties. These are dubbed “trade remedies” for a reason. And don’t forget what might be called “social dumping”—where one country literally dumps its unemployment potential elsewhere or subsidizes inefficient production forever, regardless the cost.

But what about operational mobility and the so-called benefits of financial globalization? The distinction between short-term, “hot money” and financial crises and long-term capital flows, such as foreign direct investment, is significant. One is disruptive, the other enhancing. One is patient and the other imprudent. So why is it that the timing of financial globalization and the occurrence of banking crises coincide almost perfectly?

Recurrent boom-and-bust cycles are familiar to less developed countries, but now appear to have spread to the European Union and the United States. Financial globalization has, like trade, exerted a downward pressure on the labor share of income.

Has anyone ever heard this line? “Accept lower wages, or we will move abroad!” The other week, I met a gentleman in Ohio who ran a large battery-manufacturing unit there and had recently moved, as the boss, to Mexico. I asked him about the thousands of workers in Ohio. “They are gone,” he said. “We hired far cheaper Mexican ones in Juarez at just a fraction of their hourly wage.”

Those with lower skills or qualifications are the least able to shift or move across borders and are most damaged by this sort of risk shifting. But soon, so too, will be the accountants, architects, engineers, software developers, and every other white-collar worker.

It has also become harder to tax global mobile capital. That is because capital moves to the lowest rate tax haven and uses transfer pricing to disguise profits. Taxes on labor and consumption are much easier to collect, and they have gone increasingly up and up.

Globalization, we were told, had a big upside. This is the bill of goods the public has been sold for decades. In fact, globalization has only helped the few: exporters, multinationals, and the large international banks, as well as certain professionals and the very top management.

It surely helped some countries, such as China, which rapidly transformed peasant farmers into low-cost manufacturing workers, thereby reducing poverty. But all those jobs were at the cost of “old jobs” in America’s Rust Belt. In effect, globalization was a definite and planned wealth transfer from one place to the other, which has gone largely unreported.

There is another side of the not-so-glossy globalization coin: increased domestic inequality and exacerbated social division. The benefits and monetary flows sold to the unknowing public turned out to be all one-sided and went exclusively to the very highly skilled, to employers, to cities, to cosmopolitans, and to elites—not to ordinary working people.

The United States and Europe have been ravaged by financial crises, decades without a raise in pay or the standard of living for the masses and by the effects of austerity—while the few got richer. Globalization gutted the existing social contract and ushered in a stigma of unfairness—in what is called “a rigged system.”

The playing field was hardly level. The winners took all and Goldman Sachs bankers always seemed to come out on top, whether they were selling distressed mortgage debt or shorting it (sometimes simultaneously).

In the end, the economics of globalization and of globalist agency are, we have discovered, not politically sustainable. Economic integration (in the EU or globally) has definite and unacceptable real costs that the people cannot and will not bear. This explains the rise of economic and political populism.

Economic populism and its political cousin, political populism, are a necessary antidote and a reality check to excessive globalization and globalist values and institutions. BIS be wary.

element_content=””]

About Theodore Roosevelt Malloch

Theodore Roosevelt Malloch is a scholar, diplomat, and strategist who was active in the Trump campaign in 2016.

Want news updates?

Sign up for our newsletter to stay up to date.

12 responses to “Why Populism? Globalism Isn’t Worth It

  • Last week’s speech by George W. Bush was another example of this “globalist panic.” It also appears that, as they fight back, they are becoming bolder in their rhetoric with Dubya proclaiming that the onward march of globalism is inevitable. This is a huge change from just a few years earlier when elites acted like “globalism” was a made-up conspiracy reserved for “kooks” like the Birchers and Alex Jones.

    • Anytime someone at the top tells you something is inevitable you need to stand up and fight.

  • This short article really brought my populist thoughts into sharp focus. Definitely a read-again, and needs to be widely shared. More than ever, we must MAGA, flush the Swampers once and for all.

  • I am in agreement with virtually everything you have said here with one quibble. You state, ‘The benefits of international trade as originally argued by Adam Smith and its subsequent canonization ignores important historical differences.’ This phrase strikes me as an unfair or incomplete reading of Smith. Smith never argued for ‘comparative’ advantage in a global context. Smith was clearly a nationalist and did not endorse international trade that resulted in undermining national industry. Smith promotes a notion of international trade in goods (or possibly services) that could not be produced within a given nation (or soley so) or would qualify as ‘luxury’ goods/services, not staple products/services.

  • Exactly. I can do nothing but praise this article, which lays out the true nature of international trade.

    Thank you so much for writing this.

    America grew to be the biggest economy of the world by manufacturing and developing infrastructure at home, not from exports. The idea was set forth by Hamilton, improved by the Whigs, and implemented by Lincoln and his Republican successors.

    Too bad Republucans got suckered into supporting a system against their own traditions, all in the name of fighting communism.

    Wall Street and a handful of billionaires won and everyone else lost, devastating the richest and most democractic and equal society in history.

    I hope its not too late to fix…..

    • Actually known as the American School or the National System (both names were in use). Kissinger sold us free trade in 1973, the Trade Act of 1974 was passed, with all manner of institutional papers about what we would have to do when the other countries went into debt buying so much of our stuff. Sadly, that didn’t become an issue. We have never had a trade surplus again.

      from https://www.thoughtco.com/history-of-the-us-balance-of-trade-1147456

      The History of the US Trade Deficit
      In 1975, U.S. exports exceeded foreign imports by $12,400 million, but that would be the last trade surplus the United States would see in the 20th century. By 1987, the American trade deficit had swelled to $153,300 million. The trade gap began sinking in subsequent years as the dollar depreciated and economic growth in other countries led to increased demand for U.S. exports.

      But the American trade deficit swelled again in the late 1990s.
      During this period, the U.S. economy was once again growing faster than the economies of America’s major trading partners, and Americans consequently were buying foreign goods at a faster pace than people in other countries were buying American goods.

      What’s more, the financial crisis in Asia sent currencies in that part of the world plummeting, making their goods much cheaper in relative terms than American goods. By 1997, the American trade deficit hit $110,000 million, and it was only heading higher.

  • Great article. One insight I’ve discovered over the last couple of years though is that nations are much more than economies. There certainly have been benefits of globalization to consumer choice and downward pressure on commoditized goods like food, oil, clothing, etc.. Relative to wages things today are cheaper than in the last generations and there’s definitely more choice. Our waistlines are big and our closets and TVs are bigger.

    But the author sort of touches on the real cause of social anxiety when he explains, “a home mortgage, car payments, tuition for his children, and lots of other overhead.” We live in an age of debt slavery. Left off the list is insurance which is also a financial instrument we use to avoid bankruptcy. Together, that “overhead” which we consider is mandatory for modernity is actually relatively recent invention of financial markets. Past generations couldn’t conceive of 30 year mortgages worth many multiples of yearly income. They lived in much smaller but affordable housing because no one was going to lend them that much money.

    Our modern overconsumption has created enormous costs to our financial health and, all to often, our physical health. Governments have been complicit in the enslaving of their societies. Look at all the tax breaks given to us for “overhead”. We have mortgage interest deductions, college savings deductions, health insurance deductions. Couple that with interest rates held to historically low rates for more than a generation. Consumer debt is through the roof and college debt is even greater. Our credit scores could probably make a nice stand-in for happiness meters. The higher the happier, the lower more miserable. What percentage of our lifetime incomes go to paying interest?

    Government and their conjoined banking systems aren’t “giving us enough rope to hang ourselves”. They are giving chains to enslave ourselves. A populist government would discourage the debt slavery which plagues modern developed nations. Raise interest rates to encourage saving over consumption. Quit taxing production, work and savings and start taxing consumption. Have an a cross the board tariff to protect low wage workers. End the immigration of low skilled workers.

  • Manhattan Privilege is based on transactions, not creation. The only creation they produce is Theology to protect themselves. See Manhattan Media.

  • Excellent analysis, sir – just sent to my list and will be posted in my archive. I just posted a comment with some links to more information on ‘free trade’ and its related destruction of our work environment. Please check my Disqus profile if you want to read it and/or the multiple items from my archive.

  • This short article really brought my populist thoughts into sharp focus. Definitely a read-again, and needs to be widely shared. More than ever, we must MAGA, flush the Swampers once and for all.

Comments are closed.